The Ideological Centrality of Infrastructure
The word infrastructure requires careful definition these days. Leftists have recently repositioned the word to describe not pipelines and power grids, and the like, but social services and public education. Where Leftists trod, moderate Democrats and RINOs have followed, muddying the meaning by imposing a broad concept onto what ought to be straightforward and tangible. This isn’t a trivial problem, because infrastructure, traditionally defined, demands painful clarity from ideologues committed to limited government.
For example, if you are going to build a pipeline to transport natural gas from wells to refineries, and thence to end users, you have to lay the pipe in a route that minimizes material waste. The same reality holds true for high voltage power lines, or freeways, or railroads. Without the ability of government to exercise eminent domain, it would be impossible to secure easements to build these necessary assets.
Even infrastructure that is built with private funding, such as toll roads, can’t be constructed without eminent domain. Without that legal authority, one private landowner, occupying a small parcel in the path of a project, could stop the project cold.
The moral worth of eminent domain falls along a continuum, and where the line is drawn between justified vs unjustified use is subjective. Necessary pipelines, aqueducts, and power lines are to one end, sports stadiums and urban renewal to the other. And even in those less justifiable categories, history is filled with examples of glorious rebuilt cities arising atop decaying slums, and only the arbitrary use of power made them possible. But we don’t have to go that far. We’re just trying to keep the lights on.
Regardless of your ideology, if you want your nation and the civilization it represents to endure, you have to make infrastructure a focal point of your philosophical deliberations and your political agenda, not a boring afterthought. Green ideology, now morphed into climate change extremism, backed by the most powerful institutions on Earth, has corrupted the infrastructure discussion in dangerous ways. They have stigmatized the upgrading or construction of virtually every conventional version of traditional infrastructure. New natural gas and oil pipelines, new refineries or reservoirs, aqueducts, power plants and freeways are all off the table, and we can’t even fix the old ones. Meanwhile, the infrastructure they’re building, oriented towards “renewables,” is extremely expensive and obviously inadequate.
If you’re a Democrat or a RINO, you don’t challenge green ideology. You don’t dare. Conventional infrastructure is not only environmentally incorrect, it’s also racist. The logic goes something like this: Low income neighborhoods are near infrastructure that pollutes because the pollution makes the area less desirable, lowering home values. People of color are disproportionately in low income households, therefore pollution disproportionately harms them, therefore infrastructure is racist.
That branch of libertarian ideology one might dub “Libertarianism Inc.,” pays close attention to these pieties. I recall attending a conference sponsored by libertarian mega donors a few years ago, where one of the sessions was striving to find common ground between libertarians and progressives on the issue of housing. The room was filled with earnest libertarians who seemed desperate to curry favor with the progressives on the panel. One of the popular refrains heard that day, and many times since, was that single family homes must be abolished because we must not subsidize the car. Home equals car equals road equals subsidies.
This again is pretzel logic, but now you’re playing defense on several fronts. Single family homes are “exclusionary” (translation, racist), they are unsustainable, and the infrastructure to support them drains public funds. If that isn’t enough, those public funds are now, and now more than ever, coveted by powerful public employee unions who want that money to increase their pay and shore up their pensions.
The Case for Cost-Effective Infrastructure
The argument in favor of government investment in infrastructure is not subtle. If you don’t subsidize enabling infrastructure, you will instead subsidize every household that can’t afford the higher prices that come with scarcity. In the 1950s and 1960s California was a magnet for working families (today it’s a magnet for drug addicts, vagrants and criminals) because the state government spent up to 40 percent of its general fund to build freeways, reservoirs and aqueducts.
At the same time, a deregulated private sector did its part. Energy companies were permitted to drill and refine oil and gas. Utility companies were encouraged to build natural gas and nuclear power plants. Timber companies maintained fire roads and kept high voltage transmission line corridors cleared, while harvesting and milling lumber for construction. This was a highly functional interplay between public and private interests, and the result was an environment where every basic necessity of civilization was abundant and affordable. Homes went up along with schools and parks, companies poured in to offer jobs, and everyone in California prospered.
Today the entire equation is inverted. Forty years of neglected infrastructure has led to clogged freeways, rationed water, expensive and unreliable energy, and needlessly expensive building materials. The policy response to these shortages is to zone high density multi-family “infill,” hoping to cram new residents into the footprint of existing power, water and transportation assets. Every basic necessity is now unaffordable to normal working families in California. Even food prices are rising and it’s going to get much worse, because irrigation water and fertilizer require forbidden infrastructure. Instead of fixing these mistakes, “infrastructure” is redefined as government subsidized “affordable housing,” school lunch programs, and other expensive social services that would not be necessary if genuine infrastructure were delivering affordable abundance.
The special interests that benefit from scarcity are hiding in plain sight. Public entities collect higher property tax revenue as assessments rise. Public utilities earn higher absolute profits as their regulated fixed profit percentage is calculated on far higher unit prices. High tech firms sell mandated chip sets and software that are built into “smart” appliances, and appliance manufacturers find a whole new market as existing and very durable legacy appliances are deemed obsolete before their time. Renewable energy companies sell mandated EVs, solar panels, wind turbines and batteries, nearly all of it them sourced from China. But even all this is overshadowed by how contrived scarcity creates new frontiers for financialization.
As interest rates go up, the amount any buyer can afford to borrow goes down, but the price of housing remains stable. Why? Because this time, hedge funds, sovereign wealth funds, pension funds, and institutional investors are buying everything in sight. In some cases they’re buying entire subdivisions. Cash rich, these corporate investors don’t finance their purchases, and therefore are indifferent to high interest rates.
In an era of practical investment in enabling infrastructure and reasonable instead of punitive, prohibitive regulations, the cost to build homes would drop, artificial scarcity would not exist, prices would drop, normal people could still afford homes, and America’s last great avenue for ordinary households to build generational wealth would remain intact.
Infrastructure that enables affordable abundance also benefits small businesses because it makes it easier for them to compete with larger firms. Companies that are part of an oligopoly don’t care how much their inputs cost, or how onerous regulations may become. This is one of the biggest misconceptions spread by leftists. Businesses that dominate their sectors will just pass higher costs on to their captive customers, and they welcome more regulations. They’ve realized that more regulations will help them crush emerging competitors. That’s why they’ve moved their support to the Democratic party and embraced the Green New Deal.
What a paradox. Subsidized infrastructure – along with deregulation – helps small companies compete with big companies, fostering decentralization of private wealth and a higher percentage of financially independent individuals.
Do libertarians really want to offer cover for plutocrats and the oligopolies they control? Is that the version of capitalism and competitive enterprise they embrace? Whenever a common sense infrastructure project is proposed, the green team is out to stop it. Backed by leftist billionaires and every major media property, the greens will smear the project and litigate in court. And if the outcome is nonetheless uncertain, since a lot of people recognize the need and are willing to fight for, say, more water, more energy, more roads, libertarians come in and tilt the balance to kill the project. On principle, they’ll object to any element requiring eminent domain, or use of public funds.
It’s hard to frame the ideological case for infrastructure in a seductive way. But its presence, and its absence, is felt everywhere. If principled libertarians supported infrastructure, that certainly would not preclude them from participating in revealing audits to compel more efficient use of public funds. If they reject the projects on principle, fewer get built, and those that do will lack another layer of public scrutiny.
Ultimately, libertarians have a choice: They can cozy up to progressives, exploiting the superficial synergy that finds green ideologues and small government ideologues united in stopping infrastructure projects. But then they’ll confront instead an even bigger government, funding an even more expensive, more expansive, more exploitative “infrastructure,” requiring even more subsidies. Instead of helping to fund practical conventional solutions to deliver abundant water, energy and transportation, the government will pay for smart water meters and smart appliance rebates, a renewable energy grid with all that will require, mass transit, affordable housing and housing subsidies, and social programs for the many who are economically disenfranchised by this unaffordable new world. It’s going to be one or the other.
This article originally appeared in American Greatness.
Edward Ring is a contributing editor and senior fellow with the California Policy Center, which he co-founded in 2013 and served as its first president. He is also a senior fellow with the Center for American Greatness, and a regular contributor to the California Globe. His work has appeared in the Los Angeles Times, the Wall Street Journal, the Economist, Forbes, and other media outlets.
To help support more content and policy analysis like this, please click here.
Leave a Reply
Want to join the discussion?Feel free to contribute!